Imágenes de página
PDF
ePub

limited than of carpenters and ploughmen? That is, why is it more difficult to make a man a watchmaker than a ploughman?

The chief reason is, that the education required costs a great deal more. A long time must be spent in learning the business of a watchmaker or a surgeon before a man can acquire enough skill to practise; so that, unless you have enough to support you all this time, and also to pay your master for teaching you the art, you cannot become a watchmaker or a surgeon; and no father would go to the expense of breeding up a son a surgeon or watchmaker, even though he could well afford it, if he did not expect him to earn more than a carpenter, whose education costs much less. But sometimes a father is disappointed in his expectation. If the son should turn out stupid or idle, he would not acquire skill enough to maintain himself by his business; and then the expense of his education would be lost for it is not the expensive education of a surgeon that causes him to be paid more for setting a man's leg than a carpenter is for mending the leg of a table; but the expensive education causes fewer people to become surgeons; it causes the supply of surgeons to be more limited-that is, confined to a few; and it is this limitation that is the cause of their being better paid.

So that you see the value of each kind of labour is higher or lower, like that of all other things, according as the supply is limited.

Natural genius will often have the same effect as the expensiveness of education, in causing one man to be better paid than another. For instance, one who has a natural genius for painting may become a very fine painter, though his education may not have cost more than that of an ordinary painter; and he will then earn, perhaps, ten times as much, without working any harder at his pictures than the other. But the cause why a man of natural genius is higher paid for his work than another is still the same. Men of genius are scarce; and their work, therefore, is of the more value, from being more limited in supply.

Some kinds of labour, again, are higher paid, from the supply of them being limited by other causes, and not by the cost of learning them, or the natural genius they require. Any occupation that is unhealthy, or dangerous, or disagreeable, is paid the higher on that account; because people would not otherwise engage in it. There is this kind of limitation in the supply of house-painters, miners, gunpowder-makers, and several others.

Some people fancy that it is unjust that one man should not earn as much as another who works no harder than himself. And there certainly would be a hardship, if one man could force another to work for him at whatever wages he chose to give. This is the case with those slaves who are forced to work, and are only supplied by their masters with food and other necessaries, like horses. So, also, it would be a hardship, if I were to force any one to sell me anything, whether his labour, or his cloth, or cattle, or corn, at any price I might choose to fix. But there is

no hardship in leaving all buyers and sellers free-the one to ask whatever price he may think fit, the other to offer what he thinks the article worth. A labourer is a seller of labour; his employer is a buyer of labour; and both ought to be left free.

If a man choose to ask ever so high a price for his potatoes or his cows, he is free to do so; but then it would be very hard that he should be allowed to force others to buy them at that price, whether they would or no. In the same manner, an ordinary labourer may ask as high wages

as he likes; but it would be very hard to oblige others to employ him at that rate, whether they would or no. And so the labourer himself would think, if the same rule were applied to him; that is, if a tailor, and a carpenter, and a shoemaker, could oblige him to employ them, whether he wanted their articles or not, at whatever price they chose to fix.

In former times, laws used to be often made to fix the wages of labour. It was forbidden, under a penalty, that higher or lower wages should be asked or offered for each kind of labour, than what the law fixed. But laws of this kind were found never to do any good; for when the rate fixed by law for farm-labourers, for instance, happened to be higher than it was worth a farmer's while to give for ordinary labourers, he turned off all his workmen, except a few of the best hands, and employed these on the best land only; so that less corn was raised, and many persons were out of work, who would have been glad to have had it at a lower rate, rather than earning nothing. Then, again, when the fixed rate was so low that a farmer could afford to give more to the best workmen, some farmers would naturally try to get these into their service, by paying them privately at a higher rate. And this they could easily do, so as to escape the law, by agreeing to supply them with corn at a reduced price, or in some such way; and then the other farmers were driven to do the same thing, that they might not lose all their best workmen; so that laws of this kind come to nothing.

The best way is to leave all labourers and employers, as well as all other sellers and buyers, free to ask and to offer what they think fit; and to make their own bargain together, if they can agree, or to break it off, if they cannot.

But labourers often suffer great hardships, from which they might save themselves by looking forward beyond the present day. They are apt to complain of others, when they ought rather to blame their own imprudence. If, when a man is earning good wages, he spends all as fast as he gets it in thoughtless intemperance, instead of laying by something against hard times, he may afterwards have to suffer great want when he is out of work, or when wages are lower: but then he must not blame others for this, but his own improvidence. So thought the bees in the following fable:

"A grasshopper, half starved with cold and hunger at the approach of winter, came to a well-stored beehive, and humbly begged the bees to relieve his wants with a few drops of honey. One of the bees asked him how he had spent his time all the summer, and why he had not laid up a store of food like them? Truly,' said he, 'I spent my time very merrily, in drinking, dancing, and singing, and never once thought of winter.' 'Our plan is very different,' said the bee; 'we work hard in the summer, to lay by a store of food against the season when we foresee we shall want it; but those who do nothing but drink, and dance, and sing in the summer, must expect to starve in the winter.'

COMPARING SCRIPTURE WITH SCRIPTURE.

THE danger of quoting detached passages of Scripture, without regard to their context, or to the light which other parts of God's word may throw upon their interpretation, is seen in the fact that the devil thus brought forward passages from Scripture in order to lead our Lord to sin. And such perversions of the word of God, as has been truly said, are among the deepest and most dangerous of his devices.

[merged small][graphic]

MANUFACTURE OF COTTON YARN.

HISTORY furnishes no example to compare with the rapid growth and prosperity of the cotton-trade in this country. In the early part of the eighteenth century the total quantity of cotton-wool annually imported into Great Britain did not much exceed one million pounds in weight: the quantity imported in the year 1844 amounted to 646,111,304 pounds, of which 554,196,602 pounds were retained for home consumption. When George the Third came to the throne, 1760, the entire value of all the cotton goods manufactured in Great Britain amounted to the annual sum of about two hundred thousand pounds: the declared value of our exports only, in cotton goods, amounted in the year 1844 to 25,805,3487.; while the quantity retained for home consumption is supposed to exceed in value ten millions of pounds sterling.

This astonishing progress has been made in spite of difficulties which, at first view, would appear almost insurmountable. Before the year 1790, North America (whence our present supply is chiefly obtained) did not furnish us with a single pound of cotton; and the inhabitants of Hin

dustan and China had obtained such celebrity for the lightness and delicacy of their cotton goods, as apparently to bid defiance to competition. Such, however, has been the effect of the improvements and inventions, chiefly of a few illiterate mechanics, aided by the stupendous steam-engine of Watt, that the Hindoo now intrusts the raw material to the British merchant, who, after carrying it five thousand miles to be manufactured, returns it in the form of goods which successfully rival those of Hindustan and China. The Hindoo, incessantly urging his rude spinning-wheel, produces scarcely a pound of thread in a long working day in a modern cottonmill, each spindle will produce upwards of a mile and a quarter of thread in twelve hours; and as in many mills not fewer than fifty thousand spindles are mounted, it will be found that a sufficient length of thread

may

:

be spun every day, in one of these mills, to go two and a half times round the globe.

HISTORY OF THE COTTON PLANT. Or the four raw materials which supply clothing, flax is said to have

[merged small][merged small][graphic]

HERBACEOUS COTTON.

There are many varieties of the plant, which have been divided into herbaceous cotton, shrub cotton, and tree cotton, according to the mode of growth. Of these, the most useful is the herbaceous, which is extensively cultivated in the southern parts of the United States of America, in India, China, and other warm climates. The cultivators of Georgia and the neighbouring states grow three varieties of herbaceous cotton: first, nankin cotton, bearing the yellow wool of which the well-known cloths called nankeens are made; but of this the quantity is very limited : secondly, that which is known in the country as green-seed cotton, of which the wool is white. These two grow in the midland and upland districts; and hence the white variety is known to the Liverpool dealers as Upland cotton. It is also called bowed Georgia cotton, from a method of cleaning it which will be described presently, and also short staple cotton, which refers to the length of its fibre. The third and most esteemed variety is the sea-island cotton, which is of long

(Gossypium herbaceum.)

staple, its fibre being much longer
than that of any other description:
it is strong and even, of silky texture,
and has a yellowish tinge, which, in all
cotton, when not produced by acci-
dental wetting, or by inclement sea-
sons, is regarded as a mark of su-
perior fineness. The seed of the
sea-island cotton is black, while most
of the other American cotton is pro-
duced from green seed.
It is an
annual herbaceous plant, and, being
found to thrive in the low, sandy
islands which lie along the coast from
Charleston to Savannah, the cotton
hence derives its name.

Herbaceous cotton attains a height of from eighteen to twenty-four inches; its leaves, which are of a bright dark-green colour, are marked with brownish veins, and are divided each into five lobes. The blossom expands into a pale yellow flower, which falling off, a pointed triangular pod appears, containing three cells; this gradually increases to the size of a large filbert, and becomes brown as the woolly fruit ripens; the expansion of the wool then causes the pod

to burst, when there appears a ball of snowy-white or of yellowish down, consisting of three locks, one for each cell, enclosing and firmly adhering to the seeds, which are larger than grapes, but of similar form. The appearance of a cotton-field, while the pods are progressively opening, is described as being highly interesting; "the fine dark green of the leaf contrasting beautifully with the brilliant white of the cotton suspended from the pods and floating to and fro at the bidding of the wind." Shrub cotton grows in most coun

tries where the annual herbaceous cotton is found. In the West Indies its duration is about two or three years; in India, Egypt, and some other places, it lasts from six to ten years; in the hottest countries it is perennial, and furnishes two crops a-year; in cooler climes it is annual. In appearance it is much like a currantbush.

Tree cotton grows in India, China, Egypt, and in the interior and on the western coast of Africa, and in some parts of America. It attains a height of from twelve to twenty feet.

[graphic][merged small]

The cotton-plant requires a dry, sandy soil, and thrives where the land is too poor to produce any other valuable crop. Wet seasons are usually fatal, but the vicinity of the sea is favourable to the production of the best cotton. The salt clay mud is an excellent manure, and the saline breezes promote the growth of the plant. The places in which the celebrated seaisland cotton is grown have many advantages; but, being much exposed to the inclemencies of the weather, the produce varies greatly in quality.

Great care is bestowed in America

upon the cultivation of the cottonplant. The seed is sown by hand in March and the two following months, according to the season. It is planted in rows five feet asunder, and in holes eighteen inches apart, in each of which several seeds are placed. The land is carefully weeded at short intervals; and as the plants come up, the weakest are drawn out, only two or three being left in each hole. When the plants are a few months old, they are again weeded and thinned, and the stems and branches topped off, to the extent of an inch or more from each shoot;

« AnteriorContinuar »